Governments and the UN on patent prizes

Reposting another article by Philip published in BusinessWorld on February 14, 2018.

bw
How governments can screw up the development of new drugs
by Philip Stevens

THE PATENT-BASED system of drug development will come under further pressure from key countries aiming to increase access to medicines at the executive board meeting World Health Organization in March.

Critics of the system want reform, arguing it makes drugs too expensive and fails to provide cures for those in need who may be unable to pay, such as people in developing countries. They want to slash drug prices by replacing intellectual property rights with government-funded prizes as the primary innovation incentive for medicines.

Developers of new drugs would gain government cash prize rewards for the successful development of a new medicine.

In return, companies would be forced to hand over their intellectual property rights to the government, allowing generic manufacturers to enter the market immediately. Competition between generic drug manufacturers would boost access to those in need as new drugs would be sold at their marginal cost of manufacture, so the theory goes.

Meanwhile, governments would control and plan what disease areas are rewarded by prizes, ensuring that funding is allocated to health priorities in a fair and transparent fashion.

“Delinking” the cost of R&D from the final price paid for a medicine, and making governments the funders and planners of drug development, sounds like a simple public health care solution. But so far, no country has taken the plunge.

This is not surprising; “delinkage” is not the silver bullet claimed by its supporters.

One charge leveled against the patent-based system is that it creates losses for patients by inflating medicine prices well beyond their manufacturing costs. This downplays the economic benefits of new medical technologies from averted hospitalization and fewer sick days for workers. But more to the point, an innovation system based on prizes could create just as many, if not more, economic losses.

The prizes fund would have to come from taxpayers; their burden would be at least the $141 billion spent by the private sector on R&D each year. Income tax hikes would distort labor markets and interfere with job creation.

Then there would be the added costs of the enormous new bureaucracy to manage the prizes system.

In the absence of private sector investment, which country would be willing to fill this funding gap? Here the rhetoric of many countries, including India, at World Health Organization meetings in Geneva has not been matched by serious action. Even modest WHO R&D delinkage “demonstration projects” fall $73 million short of the $85 million required, with contributions from only 10 countries.

This new world of government-funded prizes to drive medicine innovation does not look promising.

Money apart, designing prizes that work is even more of a problem. Government committees would struggle to determine the true economic and social value of medicine before it is even created.

With estimates for developing a new medicine between $1.2 billion and $2.6 billion, this matters a whole lot.

Stevens-021418-768x402For prizes lower than the true market value of the invention, drug developers — and the venture capitalists so instrumental for start-ups — would direct their capital away from medicine R&D towards politically safer but less socially useful areas. New medicines would dry up.

If a government prize committee overvalues the prize, it would trigger duplication of R&D as competitors swarm. Curious then that proponents of these prizes argue they will end the supposedly “wasteful” and duplicative R&D under the patent system.

Finally, there is the problem of politicization. A prize system would hand significant new discretionary powers to government officials as the judges of which medicines win prizes. Political factors would influence decisions on where to allocate funding, rather than clinical need. Diseases that could summon the most vocal lobby groups would get attention from prize bureaucrats, while less fashionable diseases may be ignored.

Political connections and lobbying could both play a role in securing a prize, while elected officials may attempt to influence R&D spending by government agencies.

Patents, on the other hand, represent a far less arbitrary form of innovation incentive. Government merely sets the framework of patent law, under which all companies compete. And competition is the key to innovation.

Take hepatitis C, until recently an incurable disease afflicting around 12 million Indians. Since 2013, no fewer than 10 new treatments have come onto the market, offering clinicians a huge range of options. Such breadth and speed of innovation under a winner-takes-all prize system is hard to picture.

Despite their superficial attraction, no country (other than the technologically backward former Soviet Union) has yet replaced intellectual property rights with prizes. The reasons are clear. Prizes risk economic distortions, undermining incentives for innovators, and adding a new layer of bureaucratization and politics. Be warned, therefore: delinkage and drug development do not go hand in hand.

 

Philip Stevens is director of Geneva Network, a UK-based research organization focusing on trade, innovation and health policy.

Geneva Network’s paper on data exclusivity for medicines

Minimal Government Thinkers, Inc. is a partner of two international free market network dealing with property rights protection including intellectual property rights (IPR) — the Property Rights Alliance (PRA, based in the US) and the Geneva Network (GN, based in UK). PRA is an old, established network and among its important projects is the production of theInternational Property Rights Index (IPRI) annually. GN is a new network, born only this year and it produces occasional papers and holds some public events/lectures from time to time. PRA is headed by Lorenzo Montanari and GN is headed by Philip Stevens, both are good friends of mine.

GN has produced last month a new paper, 3-pages The TPP, data exclusivity and public spending on medicines. The Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) negotiations create a number of conspiracy theories that are, well, unsubstantiated conspiracies. Like if period of regulatory data protection (RDP) aka “data exclusivity” for biologic medicines is increased, then it will increase public spending on new, essential medicines and reduce public access to them and hence, adversely affect public health.

GN Director Philip Stevens showed data that when Canada increased RDP from 0 to 8 years in 2006, it did not result in any rise in pharma expenditures/total health expenditures (THE). Japan also increased RDP from 6 to 8 years in 2007, there was no significant increase in the ratio in the succeeding years.

1
Phil concluded his paper with this observation,

“There could be many explanations for this result, ranging from changes in procurement policies to increases in the number of medicines that whose patent terms have expired. The evidence presented above, however, suggests that those concerned about access to medicines and the financial sustainability of public healthcare systems should focus their attention on policies other than Regulatory Data Protection for medicines.”
Good paper Phil, as usual.

Geneva Network’s Forum in Singapore, May 2015

Our friends and allies, Geneva Network (UK-based) and Southeast Asia Network for Development (SEANET, Malaysia-based) held a forum last May 21, 2015 in Singapore on the TPP, Health and IPR.

1

Background of  the forum:

This week, trade negotiators from some of the world’s most powerful economies are meeting in Guam to thrash out the final stages of the Trans Pacific Partnership.  This free trade agreement – which in Asia includes Singapore, Malaysia, Japan, Vietnam and Brunei – stands to become a significant milestone in the deeper integration of the global economy.

Despite the economic potential of the TPP, one of its cornerstones – stronger intellectual property rights – remains controversial, with health NGOs claiming it will impact public health by raising the price of medicines.

To what extent are such fears justified? Why is intellectual property in this trade agreement important for the future of medical innovation? And what does the TPP mean for health in the Asia region?

The speakers yesterday were:

(1) Prof Elizabeth Siew Kuan Ng, Faculty of Law, National Univ. of Singapore (NUS)

(2) Philip Stevens, Director, Geneva Network, UK

(3) Bill Claxton, Carcinoid & NeuroEndocrine Tumour Society

(4) Andrew Spiegel, Global Colon Cancer Association, and

(5) Mo Mayrides, Associate VP, PhRMA, USA.

Moderator was Dr. Debora Elms, Executive Director, Asian Trade Centre, Singapore.

I am reposting below tweets by  @SEANET_asia yesterday. All photos here are also from SEANET. Come, follow SEANET on  twitter and facebook, thanks.

(1) Prof Elizabeth Ng begins by introducing the countries involved in #TPP and how negotiation will impact the countries.

2

No one should begrudge that patent owners deserve adequate protection of returns from investment of considerable resources.

TPP Provision : Patent term extension, data exclusivity, including biologics and patent linkage.

It’s often argued that stronger IP foster econ growth, but counter agreement is flow of FDIs is not solely on property rights.

What are challenges to incorporate in regional system?

  1. Restriction on trips flexibilities eg: data exclusivity

2 : Lack of skilled patent examiners and other skilled workforce.

  1. Access to medicine for the poor : price increases and lack of access to affordable generics.

#ASEAN #TPP countries – how do you further enhance corporation with AEC happening when only 4 ASEAN countries are involved?

The tension between patent protection and access for public health is unlikely to abate.

it is understandable the pharma industry feels justified to seek stronger patent protection

Protection and access must be appropriately calibrated in order to achieve balance between public interest and private interest.

(2) Philip Stevens from @genevanetwork : It’s unlikely that there will be changes to the provisions on data inclusivity for chemical drugs.

If #IP protection increases in Malaysia, companies will set up R&D facilities.

No one has done cost benefit analysis on the impact heightened #IP provisions on the availability of medicines in developing countries.

There is a positive relationship between trade liberalisation and better health outcomes.

How? Economic liberalisation increases incomes – allows people to get better nutrition and sanitation.

(3) Bill Claxton of Carcinoid & NeuroEndocrine Tumour Society discusses how innovative medical care has improved his life.

3

As a patient advocate, I have become increasingly impressed with how pharmaceutical companies support patient groups.

#TPP we need to protect innovators and incentivise their efforts.

Clinical trial can’t work for rare diseases. Many trial fails because of trial designs.

If you look at the debate of 5/7/12 yrs for data protection – it won’t make a huge difference in rare disease community.

We are looking for a balance between protection and access between public interest and private interest.

(4) Mo Mayrides, Assoc VP of PhRMA representing industry views on #IP in the #TPP

I don’t see how the #TPP would deny governments the right to public health access.

(5) Andrew Spiegel from Global Cancer Association who traveled from Philadelphia to attend the panel this morning.

4

Patients that are diagnosed with colon cancer are living longer and more comfortably as a result of innovative biological drugs

Biologics have had tremendous impact on medicine, but there is still a long way to go

Investments will not occur in medical technology if there is no #IP protection

The scary part is if innovation stops, we would rather medicine get delayed into market than not being made all.

Open Forum, questions:

(a) Biggest barrier to #TPP is American public opinion. Do all patient advocacy groups align w your perspectives?

Andrew : Declaration of support among patient advocacy groups on #IP protection, 100 groups signed and delivered to President Obama

Bill Claxton:Patient groups are not well informed on this issue. It is possible to get a consensus view.Patient advocacy is an emerging area.

Dr Elms : Hypothetically, there is some time for patient groups to get mobilised by end of the year.

(b) Question ; How long does it take for medicine to be made and the cost?

Mo : Study from Tufts University – Cost is 2.6 USD Billion and takes 2-6 years to develop. Takes 7- 8 years before any return on investment.

Critics will say the cost is overblown. But costs have gone up in recent years.

5

Geneva Network founder and Director, Philip Stevens, 3rd from right. Great forum, Phil. Thanks.

IP News, IPN Assistance to Asian Think Tanks

Here are some IP opinions and reports  last February, related to the GIPC’s 3rd International IP Index 2015 that was released that month.

————

(1) Elevating the Global Economy through IP

by Amy O’Connor 02/09/15

http://lillypad.lilly.com/entry.php?e=6093

“Imagine spending years on research, experiencing a breakthrough, developing a new tool, technology, or medicine, but knowing that your innovation may not be protected. Many innovators around the world face this harsh reality. Intellectual property creates value – both socially and economically- by creating jobs, driving economic growth, and enriching our culture. Yet, despite these things, intellectual property protections around the globe remain inconsistent.”

(2) From The Independent, 10 February 2015:

“Innovation and creativity allows for economic growth and job opportunities – and these need to be better protected encouraging further development. Easy access should not hinder creation, MEP Therese Comodini Cachia stressed, during a European parliamentary debate about intellectual property.”

1

(3) From TGM, 10 February 2015

Reposted inMLI, same date.

“The benefits of a strong regime of property rights apply just as much to intangibles as to land and goods. We long ago worked out how to make the ownership of cars and houses and factories work, but we are not always as effective at protecting the interests of the originators of an idea, the creators of a work of art or design, or the inventors of a scientific process. Yet the benefits from clear ownership of intellectual property (IP) are every bit as clear as those flowing from the ownership of land and buildings. Those of us who watched the ease with which the private sector beat the government in mapping the human genome is but one recent example of the galvanising effect IP can have on investment in R&D.”

2

(4) From the Property Rights Alliance (PRA), 

Intellectual Property Rights (IPR) are:

– are Grounded in the Constitution

– are Deserving the Same Respect as Physical Property

– Promote Free Speech and Expression

– Are Vital to Economic Competitiveness

– Are Integral to Consumer Protection and National Security…

3

Sometime in 2009, I participated in a small group Asian think tanks’ IPR and Innovation meeting in Singapore. It was organized by the International  Policy Network (IPN) then, headed by Prof. Julian Morris. I just discovered this photo in my laptop recently. Julian (6th from left) was accompanied by Philip Stevens (whom I last saw in 2012 in Penang, Malaysia, EMHN seminar) and Alec van Gelder (whom I last saw in 2010 in Sydney, ATR-PRA conference). There were at least eight of us participants from eight Asian countries then.

4

I am thankful to IPN and Julian for introducing me to this technical topic that is often mired with emotion and populism by various campaigners advocating disrespect, if not killing, IPR.

5

Julian is a VP at Reason Foundation in the US while Philip is the founder and Director of the new global center for IPR, health and innovation, The Geneva Network.

Brand protection and safe medicines

Originally posted on May 18, 2013.

EMHN produced another good paper, Fake medicines in Asia The importance of brands to medicine quality. Authored by a good friend Philip Stevens, this six pages long paper is able to argue that corporate brand protection and brand competition coupled with rule of law, are the best way to protect the public from counterfeit and/or substandard medicines.

Fake or substandard drugs are dangerous and can be fatal. Either the patient does not get well, allowing the disease inside the body to mutate and become more serious, or the drug causes several adverse reactions and trigger more diseases and complications. 


As the “cheaper medicines” mantra is all over the country and the planet, somehow it gives an opening to dirty businessmen to offer really cheap but fake or substandard medicines. They do this by introducing unknown or lesser known brands to non-suspecting patients and drugstores. Or they simply copy the logo, brand and trademark of some known drug manufacturers, innovator or generic, and sell cheap.


The chief government regulating agency is the Food and Drugs Administration (FDA, http://www.fda.gov.ph/ in the Philippines, http://www.fda.gov/ in the US, and so on). The big problem is that this small bureau is mandated to check on the quality of (a) drugs, medicines and vaccines for humans, (b) drugs, vaccines for animals and fishes, (c) food/drink supplements and vitamins, (d) food and juice ingredients, sauces, etc., (e) perfumes, shampoo, soap, detergents, body odor spray, etc., (f) poisonous substances like insecticides and pesticides, and many others.


I think these products constitute at least 10 percent of the total output of the economy. FDA therefore, should have pharmacists, doctors, dentists, chemists, physicists, biologists, engineers, on top of having lawyers and administrators. Is it possible to have such an agency with supposedly super-technical powers and capability to minimize or control mistakes in doing its functions? I really doubt it.


One way to minimize risks and threats to public health, is to devolve product quality to the manufacturers and traders themselves, via brand protection and competition. Like “Jollibbee or McDonalds burger yan”, “Starbucks or UCC or Figaro coffee yan”, “Pfizer or GSK or Unilab or Pharex medicines yan”, “Mercury or Watsons or The Generics yan”, and so on. Consumers hold on to the brand as generally safe and these companies do all they can to avoid not even a single, not one, case of food or drinks or drug poisoning. 


Thus, products of these brands will be given minimal regulations and approval process. The main regulator for these brands and companies is the fear of being blacklisted or boycotted or sued by consumers due to bad or unhealthy products. Since these are huge if not global brands, the thought of being put in a bad light scares them more than the peering eyes of a few inspectors from the regulatory agency. Then the latter can focus their energy and resources on new products and brands. Shrewd and opportunist businessmen can put up a company and sell bad products and services that can harm public health. When the company is blacklisted, they simply close down the company and put up a “new” one and create new schemes to fool the public.


The sub-topics discussed by the paper are:


* Limits of regulation

* Brand competition and drug quality

* Intellectual property and brand integrity

* Brands are not just for multinationals

* Rule of law in defending brands

* Technological solutions to fake medicines

* Malysia’s meditag scheme

* 2D and QR barcodes

* Dangers of government-mandated technology


And the paper’s brief conclusions are:

The most fundamental cause of the spread of fake drugs in Asia has been the inability of manufacturers to protect the identity of their products. This is largely down to a lack of functioning rule of law, which makes it very difficult for manufacturers to protect their trademarks and brands via the civil and criminal courts – thereby handing a free rein to counterfeiters. The extra regulation called for by many commentators may well entrench the corrupt relationship between criminals and certain drug regulators.

Strengthening the rule of law is a vital but long-term process. In the meantime, the private sector should take advantage of its innovative capacity to experiment with different technological solutions to brand infringement. It is well placed to lead this process, as it has unparalleled access to the entire pharmaceutical supply chain, as well as the clear financial incentive to protect its revenue. Governments should encourage this process, but refrain from mandating specific technologies or systems.

This new paper is another good reference for both government administrators and healthcare advocates in the country or abroad. Markets work. And though there are indeed market failures, there are also market solutions to such failures. Government simply have to focus on only one thing: rule of law. Private players and enterprises should do what they say they are supposed to do, and not offer counterfeits or substandard if not entirely useless products and services. If they don’t, existing  governmentregulations and the penalty system should be slapped on them. No exception and no one can grant an exception. The law applies equally to unequal people.